Home »Articles and Letters » Articles » Curtailing global tax avoidance practices
Global taxation is central to global decision-making because most foreign direct investment (FDI) and global operations these days are biased by tax considerations. The numbers are huge. For instance, with around $10 trillion worth of world trade being intra-firm and a similar portion being intermediate (as opposed to finished products or services), it is the multinational firm that gets to decide internally what unit price it will type on its export invoice.

A conservative estimate has it that out of the million-odd subsidiaries or foreign affiliates of all multinationals listed in the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) 2015 database, between 300,000 and 400,000 are shell or dummy companies (firms that have no economic activity except a part-time accountant or a lawyer behind a shining brass nameplate). The entire FDI inflow statistics of major nations such as China or India are biased by the "round-tripping" of local investment masquerading as foreign investment.

In international supply chains, multinationals ship goods and services whose unit value, decided by the MNC itself, is often biased by tax considerations. Consider two firms, A and B, both owned by the same MNC. Firm A has been exporting 1,000 items per year to Firm B, invoiced at $1.30 each. But if they are invoiced at $1.80 each, B would then pay A $500 more annually. Firm A's profit would increase, and B's would decrease; but the MNC as a whole would increase its after-tax income from $2,250 to $2,325. The idea is simple: pay higher amounts to affiliates where taxes are lower, and show lower values where taxes and/or tariffs are higher.

No decision in large MNCs is made these days without assessing tax implications. The magnitude of the international tax-avoidance phenomenon-the extent to which global operations, supply chains, and location decisions are affected by tax considerations-places this issue at the heart of global strategy. In large companies, executives consider tax angles concurrently with strategy, rather than as an afterthought.

There is no world government or supranational tax authority. A world fragmented into more than 190 jurisdictions (nations) is at odds or is in tension with MNCs that look on the entire world as their blank canvas), are willing to relocate operations wherever it suits them, and may fall prey to the temptation of using the tax-avoidance techniques outlined above.

However, people at large expect companies to pay their fair share towards the common good, be they a multinational tech giant, major furniture retailer or coffee shop chain. Many countries, however, are losing out on billions of tax revenue every year by letting companies get away with moving profits to tax havens.

This is partly because of existing gaps in tax legislation. But also the increasing digitalisation of companies and widespread digital business models offer certain opportunities that companies can exploit. Unlike traditional economic systems, which relied on manufacturing and industry, many digital business models no longer need to be physically present in a country - making it easier to accumulate tax-optimised profits at a low or even zero tax rate.

That's why countries are working with their international partners to make tax fairer in the era of globalisation and digitalisation.

We need harmonised standards and multilateral cooperation in our global tax policy. After all, international challenges cannot be solved at a purely national level.

According to Rolf Bösinger (Time to pay up-published in International Politics and Society Newsletter on March 22, 2019) it's national unilateralism that companies take advantage of to move to countries that offer low tax rates. He argues that an international consensus, on the other hand, can create the pressure and obligations needed for low-tax countries to change direction and prevent companies from paying minimal tax. The OECD and G20 are said to have made significant progress in recent years by tackling base erosion and profit shifting (BEPS).

But that was said to be just the first step in the right direction, and one that addresses only certain scenarios where no tax was being paid at all. This, in the opinion of the author, doesn't cover cases of extremely low taxation, whereby just 1 per cent might be paid.

So the next step, according to him is introducing an effective minimum tax rate and closing huge tax loopholes that are perfectly legal at the moment. Doing so would directly target the cause - companies actively exploiting different tax rates - and not just play around with the symptoms.

Rolf Bösinger contends that there's nothing fundamentally wrong with tax competition. But what it should not do is create a borderless tax competition and race to the bottom. Not only does that make balancing the budget more complicated, it's unfair on hard-working people who also pay their share.

It is not just the EU that is talking about redistributing taxation rights. There are also discussions at an international level at the G20 and OECD, involving many emerging and developing countries. The G20 has commissioned the OECD to create a globally accepted standard by 2020 to ensure the digital economy is taxed properly.

That's why it has been proposed that world adopt an effective minimum tax rate. Much like the minimum wage, the idea is to ensure that multinationals pay at least a minimum tax rate, wherever they are in the world. This is not intended to massively change the long-accepted taxation principles. Only certain aspects that have already been introduced into the BEPS process will be consistently and coherently developed.

In the opinion of the author, the proposed model would essentially mean that if a subsidiary abroad is taxed on profits below a certain effective minimum tax rate, the country in question could claim the difference from the parent company. So, a set of measures is being rolled out to develop some of the BEPS recommendations even further, such as addressing hybrid structures (adoptingdifferent company forms abroad for tax advantages) and enforcing controlled foreign corporation rules (taxing domestic shareholders on the income of a foreign subsidiary).

Other targets for action considered are under capitalisation, whereby a company keeps its equity low and is financed by shareholder loans to artificially reduce profits by citing interest payments, and treaty benefits - using loopholes in international tax treaties. This also includes tackling all low-tax income - whether it is income from interest, royalty payments, services or goods - by setting a limit on low taxation.

"There would also be a ban on deducting operating expenses on low-tax payments abroad. To complement that, treaty law should be amended to ensure a contracting state is not restricted by the double taxation agreement, as long as the income is taxed at a low rate in the other state. At the moment, double taxation agreements often only prevent 'virtual double taxation', whereby there's a right to taxation but it's not exercised. But we don't live in a virtual world. We live in a real world, where there needs to be effective, not just virtual, double taxation.

"The controlled foreign corporation rules we have in Germany would therefore be strengthened, expanded and rolled out globally. This would significantly reduce the prospect for aggressive taxation structures, which digital business models, in particular, take advantage of. However, there would also be regulations put in place to set a lower limit for tax cuts to put the brakes on the ongoing race to the bottom.

"The latest tax cuts widely welcomed by companies in the US are a prime example. Tax cuts do not necessarily lead to more investment in machinery and production capacities. Often they are only used for share buybacks, benefiting the company's share price and, in turn, its shareholders, while continuing to put the state under pressure and force it into a spiral of increasing debt."

Copyright Business Recorder, 2019


the author

Top
Close
Close